Category Archives: Gold

On Gold, Deflation and Oil ..

Artist: Alexander Calder, Title: Untitled, 1963 - click for larger image
Alexander Calder ‘Untitled’

Did France cause the Great Depression?

Douglas Irwin
20 September 2010

A large body of research has linked the gold standard to the severity of the Great Depression. This column argues that while economic historians have focused on the role of tightened US monetary policy, not enough attention has been given to the role of France, whose share of world gold reserves soared from 7% in 1926 to 27% in 1932. It suggests that France’s policies directly account for about half of the 30% deflation experienced in 1930 and 1931.

A large body of economic research has linked the gold standard to the length and severity of the Great Depression of the 1930s, primarily because fixed exchange rates precluded the use of monetary policy to address the crisis (see for example Temin 1989, Eichengreen 1992, and Bernanke 1995)

But it has never been entirely clear why the gold standard produced the massive worldwide price deflation experienced between 1929 and 1933 and the enormous economic difficulties that followed. In particular, worldwide gold reserves expanded continuously through the 1920s and 1930s, so it is not obvious why the system self-destructed and produced such a cataclysm.
The standard explanation…

To explain the disaster, economic historians have pointed to the policies followed by central banks. The standard explanation for the onset of the Great Depression is the tightening of US monetary policy in early 1928 (Friedman and Schwartz 1963, Hamilton 1987). The increase in US interest rates attracted gold from the rest of the world, but the gold inflows were sterilised by the Federal Reserve so that they did not affect the monetary base. This forced other countries to tighten their monetary policies as well, without the benefit of a monetary expansion in the US. From this initial deflationary impulse came currency crises and banking panics that merely reinforced the downward spiral of prices.
… and the not-so-standard

Yet what is often overlooked is the fact that France was doing almost exactly the same thing. In fact, France was accumulating and sterilising gold reserves at a much more rapid rate than the US (see Johnson 1997 and Mouré 2002). Partly as a result of the undervaluation of the franc in 1926, the Bank of France began to accumulate gold reserves at a rapid rate. As Figure 1 shows, France’s share of world gold reserves soared from 7% in 1926 to 27% in 1932.

Figure 1. Share of world gold reserves

The redistribution of gold put other countries under enormous deflationary pressure. In 1929, 1930, and 1931, the rest of the world lost the equivalent of about 8% of the world’s gold stock, an enormous proportion – 15% – of the rest of the world’s December 1928 reserve holdings. This massive redistribution of gold would not have been a problem for the world economy if the US and France had been monetising the gold inflows. Then the gold inflows would have led to a monetary expansion in those countries, just as the gold outflows from other countries led to a monetary contraction for them. That would have been playing by the “rules of the game” of the classical gold standard. But during the interwar gold standard, there were no agreed-upon rules of the game, and both France and the US were effectively sterilising the inflows to ensure that they did not have an expansionary effect.

The sterilisation is implicit in the cover ratios presented in Figure 2. The cover ratio is the ratio of central bank gold reserves to its domestic liabilities (notes in circulation and demand deposits). Once again, the change in France is astonishing in comparison to the other countries. France’s cover ratio rose from 40% in December 1928 (the legal minimum was 35%) to nearly 80% in 1932. Between 1928 and 1932, France’s gold reserves went up 160% but the money supply (M2) did not change at all. It is not surprising that France was viewed as a “gold sink” by contemporaries.

Figure 2. Cover ratios of major central banks, 1928-1932


How strong was the deflationary pressure from US and French monetary policy?

Using 1928 as a benchmark, the amount of excess (i.e., non-monetised) gold can be calculated as the difference between the amount of gold actually held in a given year and the amount of gold required to maintain the 1928 cover ratio for the actual amount of outstanding liabilities. Figure 3 presents the results graphically and reports the excess gold as a share of the world’s gold stock.

In 1930, when the US and France held about 60% of the world’s gold stock, they were sitting on (non-monetising) about 11% of the world’s gold stock relative to 1928. Overall, US and France exerted roughly equal deflationary pressure on the rest of the world in 1929 and 1930 and France exerted a much more deflationary impact in 1931 and 1932. Over the entire period from 1928 to 1932, France had a greater deflationary impact than the US. France could have released 13.7% of the world’s gold stock, while the US could have released 11.7%, and still have maintained their 1928 cover ratios.

Figure 3. Effective reduction in world’s monetary gold stock, 1929-32


The effect on world prices

In his 1752 essay “Of Money,” David Hume remarked: “If the coin be locked up in chests, it is the same thing with regard to prices, as if it were annihilated”. So what was the effect of the effective withdrawal of this gold from circulation on the world price level? In recent research (Irwin 2010), I find that a 1% increase in the gold stock increases world prices by 1.5%. Since the US and France effectively withdrew 11% of the world’s gold stock from circulation, this would have led to a fall in world prices of about 16%. From this simple exercise, we can conclude that the Federal Reserve and Bank of France directly account for about half of the 30% deflation experienced in 1930 and 1931 (see Sumner (1991) for a different calculation that is generally consistent with this finding).

Of course, once the deflationary spiral began, other factors began to reinforce it. The most important factor was that growing insolvency (due to debt-deflation problems identified by Irving Fisher) contributed to bank failures, which in turn led to a reduction in the money multiplier as the currency to deposit ratio increased. However, these endogenous responses cannot be considered as independent of the initial deflationary impulse, and therefore US and French policies can be held indirectly responsible for at least some portion of the remaining “unexplained” part of the price decline.

In sum, economic historians have traditionally focused on the tightening of US monetary policy as the origin of the Great Depression. These findings suggest that the French contribution to the worldwide deflationary spiral deserves much greater prominence than it has thus far received.
References

Bernanke, Ben (1995), “The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 27:1-28.

Eichengreen, Barry (1992), Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939, Oxford University Press.

Friedman, Milton, and Anna J Schwartz (1963), A Monetary History of the US, 1867-1960, Princeton University Press.

Hamilton, James (1987), “Monetary Factors in the Great Depression”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 19:145-169.

Irwin, Douglas A (2010), “Did France Cause the Great Depression?”, NBER Working Paper 16350.

Johnson, H Clark (1997), Gold, France, and the Great Depression, 1919-1932,Yale University Press.

Mouré, Kenneth (2002), The Gold Standard Illusion: France, the Bank of France, and the International Gold Standard, 1914-1939, Oxford University Press.

Sumner, Scott (1991), “The Equilibrium Approach to Discretionary Monetary Policy under an International Gold Standard, 1926-1932”, The Manchester School of Economic & Social Studies, 59:378-94.

Temin, Peter (1989), Lessons from the Great Depression, MIT Press.

There are a number of implications of Irwin’s observations aside from the one that central bankers have become ‘smarter’ during the interval and would never think of shrinking the money supply. One has been iterated here often, the ‘hard currency’ effect that takes place when money becomes more valuable than the business that uses the same money for exchange. In this circumstance, money is hoarded along with what the money is proxy for, be it gold, oil or anything else. 
Put this into the context of the Austrian Creditanstalt Bank which experienced a run against deposits in 1931. Failure to bail out the bank and depositors – particularly opposed by the French government – led to its failure and those of other countries’ banks and runs against currencies. The chain of self- reinforcing failures resulted in the phenomenon of business entities ‘Hiring ‘Money’ – particularly gold. This ultimately became the world’s commerce which in turn amplified the failures of other kinds of businesses.
Banks and ‘money holders’ became gold speculators, with the big fish devouring the lesser: those with fewer (gold) resources. As in all gold regimes, those with gold withheld services to those with less including food, shelter and work; the decline in fortunes of all benefited those with gold alone, the desperate rest were left with privation.
Another implication has to do with devalued currencies being magnets for ‘value’. Money is only a marker or proxy of value; when it has little of its own it can only enable commerce. When money gains its own value it does so at the expense of commerce.
Note Irwin’s remarks leading to Figure 1:

France was accumulating and sterilising gold reserves at a much more rapid rate than the US (see Johnson 1997 and Mouré 2002). Partly as a result of the undervaluation of the franc in 1926, the Bank of France began to accumulate gold reserves at a rapid rate. As Figure 1 shows, France’s share of world gold reserves soared from 7% in 1926 to 27% in 1932.

Compare this effect to China’s undervaluation of its currency and the resulting accumulation – and sterilization – of reserves both in dollars and otherwise. In effect, China is exporting deflation the same way France exported deflation during the run- up to the 1929 stock crash in the US. Both France and the US were hell- bent on importing gold – from any and all sources – in the period leading up to the US going off gold in 1933.
Currently the issue is petroleum and other ‘energy’ resources such as the rare- earth metals used in wind turbines and solar panels  which are accumulated just the same as ‘gold resources’ were accumulated by means of undervalued francs and dollars.

China increasing economic leverage by limiting ‘rare earths’ exports

China’s recent move to limit exports of minerals critical in the manufacture of a vast array of products such as missiles, car batteries, cellphones, lasers and computers is stoking alarm that its domination of the industry could give it enhanced leverage over the United States.


On Thursday, some traders of “rare earths,” 17 minerals that are used in small portions in almost every advanced industrial product, reported that China, which controls 97 percent of the industry, had halted the export of anything that contained traces of the minerals to Japan. The Chinese government denied the allegation. 

“Rare earth materials are essential for our country’s technological competitiveness and our national security, yet China is cornering the market and we are falling behind,” said Rep. Kathy Dahlkemper …

For years, China has worked to dominate the rare earths industry. Starting in the late 1980s and early 1990s, China flooded the world with cheap rare earths. It sold neodymium and samarium, which form the basis of extraordinarily powerful magnets needed for precision-guided missile systems and the batteries used in hybrid or electric vehicles. It mined europium, which forms the basis of the high-efficiency lighting industry; lanthanum, without which it would be difficult to refine gas; and cerium, which is used to polish the glass on computer screens and cellphones. 

China’s prices were so low that it led the once-biggest mine in the world – Mountain Pass in California – to shut its operations in 2002 after allegations of environmental violations at the facility.”In the Western world, people were happy to give the Chinese this job,” said Jaakko Kooroshy, an analyst at The Hague Centre for Strategic Studies. “Mining rare earths is a dirty business. It is environmentally really dangerous.


So, the trade war intensifies, an outgrowth of purposefully depressed currency exchange rates. Here, the monopoly power to withhold services manifests itself. There is no reason to believe that producers of other forms of energy are not paying attention. Consider:
In his 1752 essay “Of Money,” David Hume remarked: “If the coin be locked up in chests, it is the same thing with regard to prices, as if it were annihilated”. So what was the effect of the effective withdrawal of this gold from circulation on the world price level? In recent research (Irwin 2010), I find that a 1% increase in the gold stock increases world prices by 1.5%. Since the US and France effectively withdrew 11% of the world’s gold stock from circulation, this would have led to a fall in world prices of about 16%.
While gold was a de jure monetary instrument, it is clear that crude oil is now- becoming a defacto one. What is the deflationary implication of the removal of crude oil and other energy analogs from circulation? The deflationary implications of ‘money renting’ along with hoarding (as the Chinese are doing with their rare- earth metals) are profound.
The Consequences of Less
In 1940 the German army invaded France and occupied the country. The French minister who presided over the bungled bail out of Creditanstalt, Pierre Laval, became the Vichy collaborator to the Germans. At the end of the war, he was executed by the French by firing squad . 
Events have a way of entangling all whose arrogance and short- sightedness perceives only advantages for themselves. Laval opposed the funding of a Creditanstalt rescue on the grounds that doing so could only take place in the absence of a proposed German- Austrian customs union. The outcome of Laval’s opposition was both the bank failure along with a sense of French persecution in Germany. This insecurity inflamed the large and growing cadre of militant extremists including the National Socialists who railed against French strangulation of German trade. China can only see advantages to itself by controlling access to alternative energy support. 
Sow the wind, reap the whirlwind …
It’s Ben Bernanke v. Planet Earth as the Fed attempts to kill the dollar one more time and spur inflation. Brent crude is $79+ change – Nymex Crude + $76. Is another run @ $80 taking place? The S&P seems to think so. Can the hapless crude customers withstand prices over $75? Time will tell, but the recent past suggests that Bernanke will fail as he has repeatedly and oil prices will fall again.